New study shows 'informal taxation' in developing countries is far greater than suspected

Developing countries often lack the official government structure needed to collect taxes efficiently. This lack of systematic tax collection limits the ability of those countries to provide public services that aid growth, such as roads, sanitation and access to water.
But a new study co-authored by MIT economist Benjamin Olken reveals that developing countries actually have extensive informal systems in which citizens contribute money and labor to public-works projects. In effect, local governments in the developing world collect more taxes and produce more public goods than many outsiders have realized, a finding with implications for aid groups and governments trying to decide how to fund anti-poverty projects worldwide.
鈥淚t鈥檚 really surprising just how many people are doing this, and how prevalent this is,鈥 says Olken, an associate professor in MIT鈥檚 Department of Economics. 鈥淭his is a very common facet of how people experience life in a lot of developing countries. It鈥檚 supporting a large share of what鈥檚 going on at the village level.鈥
These informal taxes are generally regressive: While better-off citizens contribute more than the poor do in absolute terms, the percentage of income they pay is lower than the percentage of income that the poor pay. Because organizations such as World Bank sometimes recommend that governments use local co-financing of public-works projects, that means some programs intended to help curb poverty may actually place a larger relative tax burden on the poor.
鈥淔or aid groups, it鈥檚 useful to know what the distributional implications will be, and compare that to other financing mechanisms,鈥 Olken says. 鈥淚 hope that people will start thinking about these implications.鈥
Have asphalt, will organize
The research is presented in a new paper, 鈥,鈥 by Olken and co-author Monica Singhal, an associate professor of public policy at the Harvard Kennedy School of Government. They examined 10 countries in the developing world and found that in many cases, more than 50 percent of citizens participate in these informal, local taxation schemes. In only one of the 10 nations did fewer than 20 percent of citizens pay additional informal taxes.
That changes our picture of taxation in the developing world. Previous studies have shown that formal, official taxation of households only accounts for 18 percent of taxes collected in the developing world, as opposed to 45 percent of taxes collected in the developed world. Given this fact, informal taxes provide a significant boost to local authorities: In Indonesia, for instance, informal taxes increase the amount of revenue under local control by more than 50 percent.
To conduct the study, Olken, Singhal and assistants from MIT鈥檚 Undergraduate Research Opportunities Program examined more than 100 existing field-research surveys, including the World Bank Living Standards Measurement Survey. Those surveys each have sample sizes ranging from about 1,500 to 30,000 people. The countries included in the paper are Albania, Ethiopia, Guatemala, Indonesia, Nigeria, Nicaragua, Panama, the Philippines, Vietnam and Zambia.
The paper is scheduled for publication in the American Economic Journal: Applied Economics later in 2011.
One impetus for the research came from Olken鈥檚 own experiences in Indonesia, where he has conducted field research for about a decade. In a village where he was once staying, Olken recalls, 鈥渢he district government dropped off 29 drums of asphalt, and that was it. So the village had to decide what to do. They had a meeting, figured out how much they needed to pave a road in terms of money and labor, and basically went around the room and assigned contributions to people.鈥
Researchers have been aware that such practices existed; in Indonesia, these informal systems are called gotong royang, and in Kenya they are called harambee. But while the existing data Olken and Singhal used, such as the World Bank surveys, contain information about local life, that information had not previously been pieced together to create a picture of local taxation practices.
鈥淲e鈥檙e not the first people to have noticed this phenomenon, but I think this is the first paper to treat it like a tax issue,鈥 Olken says.
鈥淭hey mentioned the elephant in the room,鈥 says Erzo Luttmer, an associate professor of economics at Dartmouth College. 鈥淎sking people to contribute labor to road projects, or to contribute money to replacing the roof on a school building, is a real tax, but it doesn鈥檛 show up in most statistics. Nobody had inquired as thoroughly into it until now.鈥
Give me your money or your labor
Among the quirks of informal taxation in the developing world, Olken notes, is that 鈥渋t鈥檚 not formally enforced through the legal system.鈥 And yet, the size of people鈥檚 contributions is not quite voluntary. About 84 percent of households in the survey data report that their levels of taxation are assigned by village or neighborhood leaders.
In many places, those payments can be made either by cash, or by contributing labor to the public-works projects. 鈥淭he poorer people tend to contribute more in kind, and the richer people tend to do more in cash,鈥 Olken says.
As Olken notes, that option 鈥 paying by labor or cash 鈥 constitutes what economists call an 鈥渙ptimal screening mechanism,鈥 which adds to the knowledge local leaders have about their neighbors. 鈥淭his kind of device, letting people do either in cash or in kind, can be a way of getting people 鈥 to reveal some information about themselves that you might otherwise not know.鈥
Luttmer hopes future research will help scholars further understand how citizens make these kinds of decisions. 鈥淎re people taxed when they have time to contribute labor?鈥 he asks. 鈥淚f it鈥檚 harvest time, do they have their children or wives attend to their own fields while they contribute labor to the common pool? Which systems lead to the most regressive forms of taxation, and which lead to more progressive tax burdens?鈥
This story is republished courtesy of MIT News (), a popular site that covers news about MIT research, innovation and teaching.
Provided by Massachusetts Institute of Technology